Melnikov (2001)
These notes are based on the following article:
Melnikov, Oleg (2001). Demand for Differentiated Durable Products: The Case of the U.S. Computer Printer Market. Unpublished manuscript, Yale University.
Introduction
- A dynamic model of demand for differentiated durable goods.
- Differentiated in many other dimensions in addition to price.
- Durables yield consumption services over many periods.
- Quality evolves over time.
- Problems with static discrete choice model:
- Assumes consumers participate every period.
- Predict consistent upward trend in sales due to improving quality and falling prices.
- Cannot account for intertemporal demand substitution.
- The dynamic model is estimated using a two-stage approach.
- The model is applied to the computer printer market to test the hypothesis of forward-looking consumers.
Model
- Discrete time .
- Consumers each have unit demand over lifetime.
- Consumer ’s state (own product or not) is . Effective market size at time is .
- Set of products available at time is .
- If consumer purchases product at time , the payoff is otherwise, the consumer obtains payoff for one period.
- Static product characteristics , dynamic product characteristics , and preferences .
- Note: the assumption of strict unit demand will be relaxed later by allowing for consumers to re-enter the market by introducing replacement demand.
Assumptions
- Consumers share a common discount factor .
- Consumer preferences are homogeneous: for all .
- The terms are independent across and and follow the GEV distribution with CDF .
- Then, for a representative consumer, we can write the payoff as
- Note: The function must satisfy a few standard assumptions for the GEV distribution.
Consumer’s Problem
- First, given realizations of at time , consumers determine which product would maximize their utility.
- Then, the consumer decides whether to purchase the product or wait until next period. This generates an optimal stopping problem
- Here, denotes the conditional expectation given the information available to all consumers at time .
- Thus, if we knew the distribution of , we could formulate this as a standard dynamic discrete choice problem.
Consumer’s Problem: Reformulation
- Define
- Given the GEV assumption, has a Type I Extreme Value distribution with CDF
- is the mode of the distribution and is effectively a scalar sufficient statistic for the distribution of future payoffs.
- Now, we can write the Bellman equation:
Notes:
Here, the GEV assumption allows us to reformulate the problem on a significantly smaller state space. Previously, we had to account for the mean utility level of each product (i.e., each for ). Now, acts as an index of the entire market and is the only state we need to keep track of.
For the Type 1 Extreme Value Distribution, we would have .
Supply
- In order to solve the consumer’s problem, we need to know how products are evolving.
- This includes prices, attributes, and the set of available products.
- However, we saw before that the distribution of was characterized completely by a scalar variable .
- can be thought of as the value of being a consumer in the market as a whole.
- Rather than try to model the process explicitly, Melnikov assumes that it is a Markov process with transition density .
- We specify a functional form for , namely that follows a diffusion process where the are iid standard Normal.
Diffusion Process
and must satisfy the following properties:
- and are continuous and differentiable a.e.
- for all .
- is a weak submartingale: .
- where , , and .
Solving the Consumer’s Problem
Under the previous assumptions, we can write \eqref{bellman} as where has a Type 1 Extreme Value distribution with mode and is the reservation utility. This is an optimal stopping problem with stopping set
Demand
- The consumer will buy a product at time if and only if .
- Therefore, the probability of postponing is implied by the model:
- We can also define the hazard rate of product adoption:
- Product-specific purchase probabilities:
Hazard Rate
- The reservation utility only affects the choice probabilities through the hazard rate .
- The hazard rate is a monotone transformation of .
- We can derive a functional equation for .
- Note that where follows the mode zero extreme value distribution.
- We then have
- And therefore,
Hazard Rate: Numerical solutions
- We can solve the previous functional equation numerically: where
- Requires only one dimensional numerical integration.
- Once we know , we can find the hazard rate and choice probabilities.
Aggregation
Integrate over the joint distribution of and to obtain aggregate demand.
Assumption: and for all .
Transition of consumer state follows where is an exogenous “break-down” probability, allowing consumers to return to the market.
The participation rate evolves according to:
The implied market shares are
Econometric specification
The econometrician observes:
- : sales of product in period .
- : total market size (taken to be number of households).
- : vector of static product attributes.
- : vector of dynamic product attributes.
Define the following:
- Total sales of product : .
- Absolute market shares: . Relative market shares: .
Estimation: Static Parameters
- Taking the natural log of the ratio of to gives
- We can estimate these parameters using the sample analog of via OLS.
- Use estimated time effects as estimates of the realizations of the market quality process.
Estimation: Transition Kernel
- Estimate the parameters of the diffusion process.
- Using estimated ’s, we can estimate using the functional form of the transition kernel via Maximum Likelihood.
Estimation: Dynamic Parameters
- We have , so for any , we can evaluate , the hazard function, and the purchase probabilities.
- Let denote the number of consumers shopping for a new product.
- Then, the expected level of aggregate sales is
- The number of consumers who are shopping next period equals the number who choose to continue searching this period plus the replacement demand inflow plus any exogenous change in the market size:
- Thus, the remaining parameters , , and can be found using \eqref{expagsales} and \eqref{kolchap} to fit predicted sales to the data:
Monte Carlo Results
- are iid Type 1 Extreme Value.
- where
- Static logit model attributes variance in market shares only to differences in product fixed effects, ignoring any dynamics.
U.S. Printer Market
- In 1998, printer sales accounted for 21% of total retail sales of computers and accessories, totaling 4.5 billion dollars.
- In the five years after 1998, unit sales growth was 12%.
- Product differentiation in many dimensions such as:
- Technology: inkjet vs. laser, color vs. black and white.
- Functionality: printers vs. all-in-one devices.
- Target sector: personal vs. workgroup.
- Highly concentrated industry with four-firm concentration ratio of 91% (HP, Epson, Canon, Lexmark).
Data Sources
- Primary source: Hardware Monthly Report by PC Data, Inc.
- Consists of point-of-sale scaner level data on computer products sold by major retailers, mail order firms, and web sites.
- This subset contains monthly sales figures and average prices of printers and multifunction devices.
- Dates included: 14 months from January 1998 to February 1999.
- Estimated market coverage: 55%.
- Secondary source: static printer characteristics from various sources such as CNET, CompUSA, and online documentation.
- Resulting sample: 462 models from 27 manufacturers.
- Descriptive statistics: Table 5.3, page 26.
Descriptive Statistics
- Between January 1998 to January 1999, average sales-weighted price of a printer fell by almost 16%. Lasers more expensive by 5% and inkjets less expensive by 20%.
- All technological factors such as speed, number of colors, and resolution have clear upward trends, especially installed RAM.
- Market share and revenue by speed and resolution (Figure 5.1, page 28).
- After controlling for quality, prices fell by 30%.
- Overall, market dynamics seem to be very important.
Estimation
- Parametric specification:
- is taken to be the number of households with at least one computer.
- No instruments available for price, use fixed effects for price groups.
Empirical Results
- Static structural parameters: Table 5.6.
- Most parameters behave as expected except RAM.
- Strong negative effect for refurbished hardware.
- Brand names appear to be very important.
- Demand is most elastic for very low and very high price printers.
- Dynamic structural parameters: Table 5.7.
- Strong support for forward-looking consumer behavior.
- Replacement probability (0.02) implies printer lifetime of 4 years.
- Two constrained models: myopic () and patient ().
Conclusions
- Benefits of the model:
- A first step towards endogenous reentry of consumers.
- Quality and choice set may evolve over time.
- Allows for intertemporal demand substitution.
- What’s lacking:
- Supply side: product introduction, entry, and exit.
- Data: only retail sales, no institutional purchases.
- Market quality continues to grow relative to outside good.
- No secondary market.